7 Things to Know about California’s New Solar Panel Policy

By Mia Nakaji Monnier

Earlier this month, California became the first state to require all new homes to have solar power. The mandate, which comes from the California Energy Commission (CEC), will take effect in 2020, making solar power even more common in a state that already boasts about half the country’s solar generating capacity. Part of the motivation for the new policy is California’s ambitious goal to be producing 50% of the state’s energy from renewable sources by 2030.

If a policy that lowers reliance on fossil fuels sounds like a win, especially under an administration that refuses to acknowledge climate change, the controversy surrounding this move, even among alternative energy advocates, is surprising. Energy economists in particular argue that a rooftop solar mandate is an expensive and inefficient way to address climate change. On the morning of their vote, UC Berkeley Haas School of Business professor Severin Borenstein emailed the CEC to urge them not to approve the mandate. Here are seven things you should know about the policy, and why experts are arguing about it:

1. The solar mandate doesn’t require all new homes to have solar panels.

New homes can either get their electricity from rooftop panels or from a shared solar grid that serves multiple homes. Even among rooftop solar panel options, there’s some flexibility. Solar arrays can either be purchased outright or leased, and must be a minimum of 2 to 3 kilowatts (according to the New York Times, most home solar arrays are two to three times that size).

2. Solar panels will make new homes more expensive but should result in savings over time.

The CEC estimates that its new standards (which include the solar mandate as well as other building efficiency rules related to issues like insulation and ventilation) add $9,500 to the cost of a new home but save $19,000 on electricity over 30 years. In an analysis in Vox, David Roberts wrote that the commission probably overestimated costs (because the price of solar panels is already falling, and panels for new developments will likely be bought in bulk), meaning savings for solar customers will likely be even higher. Most solar panels come with a 25- to 30-year warranty, and while they will be less efficient at that age, they can still produce electricity. Plus, as technology improves, so does solar panel longevity.

3. Solar panels won’t fill all your energy needs, unless you have a battery.

When you pay your utility for electricity, a significant portion of your bill goes toward grid maintenance. The more people who opt out in favor of solar, the more that cost shifts to the remaining utility customers.

Even when you have rooftop solar panels, you’ll most likely still rely on the grid for some of your electricity. The power your panels produce has to be used or stored in a battery immediately, and any excess goes to the grid where it can serve other buildings in your area. Batteries aren’t just useful for nighttime energy needs; they also provide extra protection against power outages caused by earthquakes or other natural disasters. Still, batteries can be expensive, typically costing $5,000 or more.

And because of a program called “net metering,” solar customers haven’t had much incentive to buy batteries. If you qualify for net metering (which you can apply for through your utility), you’ll receive credits for the power you provide, which you can use to buy power from the grid during the non-solar producing hours of the day.

4. Going solar makes the grid more expensive for everyone else.

This is a major part of the argument against the solar mandate. When you pay your utility for electricity, a significant portion of your bill goes toward grid maintenance. The more people who opt out in favor of solar, the more that cost shifts to the remaining utility customers. Lucas Davis, another Haas professor, wrote a post about this on the Energy Institute blog, titled “Why Am I Paying $65/year for Your Solar Panels?” He sees the mandate as an unnecessarily expensive way to increase alternative energy production.

However, California recently switched to a new form of net metering that takes into account time of use, which means customers will be paid at a lower rate for the solar energy they provide the grid during the hours of lowest electricity demand. Davis said this will help lessen the problem of cost-shifting.

5. Some think solar farms in the desert would be a better alternative.

Davis is among the energy economists who see grid-scale solar, or vast desert solar farms, as a better way to approach solar energy. He and fellow Haas professor Catherine Wolfram estimate it to be three times cheaper than rooftop solar, since it’s easier to install and maintain and can be placed somewhere with optimal sunlight. Wolfram also argues that it has the potential to make a bigger global impact.

“California produces a small share of world greenhouse gas emissions, so if we really want to help solve this global problem, we should be thinking about things we can do that will help India, China, Sub-Saharan Africa cause fewer greenhouse gas emissions,” Wolfram said. “So if we’re pushing something that is more expensive, like rooftop and not grid-scale, then to the extent we’re setting an example for the rest of the world, we’re setting the wrong example.”

Residential and commercial buildings combined are responsible for the least greenhouse gas emissions, compared to others like agriculture and, the worst offender,
transportation.

6. Hawaii may offer a model for better rooftop solar.

In a response to the criticism from Davis and other energy economists, Ethan Elkind, Director of the Climate Program at the Center for Law, Energy & the Environment, wrote a blog post pointing to Hawaii as a model for how to make rooftop solar work. Utilities in Hawaii pay solar customers for surplus energy at a lower, wholesale rate, which has offset cost-shifting and in turn, encouraged people to buy batteries.

Elkind thinks California’s new net metering policy shows we’re moving toward this model, but he also argues that locally sourced energy provides a benefit to others on the grid: It saves the utility from having to ship in electricity from greater distances, which is not only expensive but also results in power loss along the way.

7. Private residences are not the biggest polluters in California, so the solar mandate won’t make that much of a difference by itself.

According to the Energy Information Administration, residential and commercial buildings combined are responsible for the least greenhouse gas emissions, compared to others like agriculture and, the worst offender, transportation. In fact, Elkind points out that the estimated emission reduction for all the CEC’s new standards combined700,000 metric tons over three yearsis tiny compared to the total amount of greenhouse gases emitted in California, about 440 million metric tons per year. “I wouldn’t call it a drop in the bucket, but it’s not by itself going to be our single most important strategy,” Elkind said. “But it is an important one.”

Share this article:
Google+ Reddit

Comments

Ref the argument against this measure from Professor Lucas Davis linked to above: Dr. Davis made a few errors in his argument for not allowing full net metering. One is assuming in his calculations that there are no payments made to offset the fixed costs of the utility. California does allow the transmission and other fixed costs to be recovered. With my new solar panels I pay almost $25/month to PG&E for their fixed costs, far more than the $65/year (just over $5/month) that Dr. Davis calculates. Another oversight is that the solar generation (from whatever source) comes at mid-day which *used to be* the peak grid power consumption period. To satisfy this mid-day demand very, very expensive “peaker plants” (usually natural gas) were built and staffed to run just a few hours a day. Adding solar eliminated a lot of that very high extra marginal cost and shifted the much-diminished peak to late afternoon. The marginal cost of avoided peak generation needs to be included. Another error in Dr. Davis’ back-of-the-envelope calculations is the cost of land for solar panels. That is non-trivial in $ terms. It is also significant in that much open space in CA suitable for solar farms is likely either a fire hazard area, a natural protected space for various species of flora and fauna, or farmland. It is preferable to use already occupied space and a $ cost on that value should be included. Yet another error in Dr. Davis’ calculations is the cost of transmission capacity for all the remote solar in the central valley or wherever the utility can find space. That is decidedly non-trivial. Usually power generation is not too far from consumption so the marginal cost of additional lines needs to be included. Further, the transmission lines between remote solar generation and electricity use are often not usable because at peak times the lines in the grid near use areas are full. As a result, the power from the remote solar is sent to Arizona. PG&E and other utilities actually pay the Arizona utility to take CA solar. The AZ utility in turn shuts off the locally generated solar in AZ. These costs should be included in Dr. Davis’ calculations. Yet another error in his article reads: “Fortunately, the California Energy Commission has *poured* over solar radiation information…”. It should be “pored” - “verb (used without object), pored, por·ing: to read or study with steady attention or application.” Fortunately, the CEC acted as it did despite Dr. Davis’ letter.
You might consider a “reply” program that allows spacing and paragraphs.
Interested in current information

Add new comment